Not all uses of data are equal

Gil Press worries that “big data enthusiasts may encourage (probably unintentionally) a new misguided belief, that ‘putting data in front of the teacher’ is in and of itself a solution [to what ails education today].”

As an advocate for the better use of educational data and learning analytics to serve teachers, I worry about careless endorsements and applications of “big data” that overlook these concerns:

1. Available data are not always the most important data.
2. Data should motivate providing support, not merely accountability.
3. Teachers are neither scientists nor laypeople in their use of data. They rely on data constantly, but need representations that they can interpret and turn into action readily.

Assessment specialists have long noted the many uses of assessment data; all educational data should be weighed as carefully, even more so when implemented at a large scale which magnifies the influence of errors.

Advertisements

If assessments are diagnoses, what are the prescriptions?

I happen to like statistics. I appreciate qualitative observations, too– data of all sorts can be deeply illuminating. But I also believe that the most important part of interpreting them is understanding what they do and don’t measure. And in terms of policy, it’s important to consider what one will do with the data once collected, organized, analyzed, and interpreted. What do the data tell us that we didn’t know before? Now that we have this knowledge, how will we apply it to achieve the desired change?

In an eloquent, impassioned open letter to President Obama, Education Secretary Arne Duncan, Bill Gates and other billionaires pouring investments into business-driven education reforms (revised version at Washington Post), elementary teacher and literacy coach Peggy Robertson argues that all these standardized tests don’t give her more information than what she already knew from observing her students directly. She also argues that the money that would go toward administering all these tests would be better spent on basic resources such as stocking school libraries with books for the students and reducing poverty.

She doesn’t go so far as to question the current most-talked-about proposals for using those test data: performance-based pay, tenure, and firing decisions. But I will. I can think of a much more immediate and important use for the streams of data many are proposing on educational outcomes and processes: Use them to improve teachers’ professional development, not just to evaluate, reward and punish them.

Simply put, teachers deserve formative assessment too.

Statistical issues with applying VAM

There’s a wonderful statistical discussion of Michael Winerip’s NYT article critiquing the use of value-added modeling in evaluating teachers, which I referenced in a previous post. I wanted to highlight some of the key statistical errors in that discussion, since I think these are important and understandable concepts for the general public to consider.

  • Margin of error: Ms. Isaacson’s 7th percentile score actually ranged from 0 to 52, yet the state is disregarding that uncertainty in making its employment recommendations. This is why I dislike the article’s headline, or more generally the saying, “Numbers don’t lie.” No, they don’t lie, but they do approximate, and can thus mislead, if those approximations aren’t adequately conveyed and recognized.
  • Reversion to the mean: (You may be more familiar with this concept as “regression to the mean,” but since it applies more broadly than linear regression, “reversion” is a more suitable term.) A single measurement can be influenced by many randomly varying factors, so one extreme value could reflect an unusual cluster of chance events. Measuring it again is likely to yield a value closer to the mean, simply because those chance events are unlikely to coincide again to produce another extreme value. Ms. Isaacson’s students could have been lucky in their high scores the previous year, causing their scores in the subsequent year to look low compared to predictions.
  • Using only 4 discrete categories (or ranks) for grades:
    • The first problem with this is the imprecision that results. The model exaggerates the impact of between-grade transitions (e.g., improving from a 3 to a 4) but ignores within-grade changes (e.g., improving from a low 3 to a high 3).
    • The second problem is that this exacerbates the nonlinearity of the assessment (discussed next). When changes that produce grade transitions are more likely than changes that don’t produce grade transitions, having so few possible grade transitions further inflates their impact.
      Another instantiation of this problem is that the imprecision also exaggerates the ceiling effects mentioned below, in that benefits to students already earning the maximum score become invisible (as noted in a comment by journalist Steve Sailer

      Maybe this high IQ 7th grade teacher is doing a lot of good for students who were already 4s, the maximum score. A lot of her students later qualify for admission to Stuyvesant, the most exclusive public high school in New York.
      But, if she is, the formula can’t measure it because 4 is the highest score you can get.

  • Nonlinearity: Not all grade transitions are equally likely, but the model treats them as such. Here are two major reasons why some transitions are more likely than others.
    • Measurement ceiling effects: Improving at the top range is more difficult and unlikely than improving in the middle range, as discussed in this comment:

      Going from 3.6 to 3.7 is much more difficult than going from 2.0 to 2.1, simply due to the upper-bound scoring of 4.

      However, the commenter then gives an example of a natural ceiling rather than a measurement ceiling. Natural ceilings (e.g., decreasing changes in weight loss, long jump, reaction time, etc. as the values become more extreme) do translate into nonlinearity, but due to physiological limitations rather than measurement ceilings. That said, the above quote still holds true because of the measurement ceiling, which masks the upper-bound variability among students who could have scored higher but inflates the relative lower-bound variability due to missing a question (whether from carelessness, a bad day, or bad luck in the question selection for the test). These students have more opportunities to be hurt by bad luck than helped by good luck because the test imposes a ceiling (doesn’t ask all the harder questions which they perhaps could have answered).

    • Unequal responses to feedback: The students and teachers all know that some grade transitions are more important than others. Just as students invest extra effort to turn an F into a D, so do teachers invest extra resources in moving students from below-basic to basic scores.
      More generally, a fundamental tenet of assessment is to inform the students in advance of the grading expectations. That means that there will always be nonlinearity, since now the students (and teachers) are “boundary-conscious” and behaving in ways to deliberately try to cross (or not cross) certain boundaries.
  • Definition of “value”: The value-added model described compares students’ current scores against predictions based on their prior-year scores. That implies that earning a 3 in 4th grade has no more value than earning a 3 in 3rd grade. As noted in this comment:

    There appears to be a failure to acknowledge that students must make academic progress just to maintain a high score from one year to the next, assuming all of the tests are grade level appropriate.

    Perhaps students can earn the same (high or moderate) score year after year on badly designed tests simply through good test-taking strategies, but presumably the tests being used in these models are believed to measure actual learning. A teacher who helps “proficient” students earn “proficient” scores the next year is still teaching them something worthwhile, even if there’s room for more improvement.

These criticisms can be addressed by several recommendations:

  1. Margin of error. Don’t base high-stakes decisions on highly uncertain metrics.
  2. Reversion to the mean. Use multiple measures. These could be estimates across multiple years (as in multiyear smoothing, as another commenter suggested), or values from multiple different assessments.
  3. Few grading categories. At the very least, use more scoring categories. Better yet, use the raw scores.
  4. Ceiling effect. Use tests with a higher ceiling. This could be an interesting application for using a form of dynamic assessment for measuring learning potential, although that might be tricky from a psychometric or educational measurement perspective.
  5. Nonlinearity of feedback. Draw from a broader pool of assessments that measure learning in a variety of ways, to discourage “gaming the system” on just one test (being overly sensitive to one set of arbitrary scoring boundaries).
  6. Definition of “value.” Change the baseline expectation (either in the model itself or in the interpretation of its results) to reflect the reality that earning the same score on a harder test actually does demonstrate learning.

Those are just the statistical issues. Don’t forget all the other problems we’ve mentioned, especially: the flaws in applying aggregate inferences to the individual; the imperfect link between student performance and teacher effectiveness; the lack of usable information provided to teachers; and the importance of attracting, training, and retaining good teachers.

Some history and context on VAM in teacher evaluation

In the Columbia Journalism Review’s Tested: Covering schools in the age of micro-measurement, LynNell Hancock provides a rich survey of the history and context of the current debate over value-added modeling in teacher evaluation, with a particular focus on LA and NY.

Here are some key points from the critique:

1. In spite of their complexity, value-added models are based on very limited sources of data: who taught the students, without regard to how or under what conditions, and standardized tests, which are a very narrow and imperfect measure of learning,

No allowance is made for many “inside school” factors… Since the number is based on manipulating one-day snapshot tests—the value of which is a matter of debate—what does it really measure?

2. Value-added modeling is an imprecise method whose parameters and outcomes are highly dependent on the assumptions built into the model.

In February, two University of Colorado, Boulder researchers caused a dustup when they called the Times’s data “demonstrably inadequate.” After running the same data through their own methodology, controlling for added factors such as school demographics, the researchers found about half the reading teachers’ scores changed. On the extreme ends, about 8 percent were bumped from ineffective to effective, and 12 percent bumped the other way. To the researchers, the added factors were reasonable, and the fact that they changed the results so dramatically demonstrated the fragility of the value-added method.

3. Value-added modeling is inappropriate to use as grounds for firing teachers or calculating merit pay.

Nearly every economist who weighed in agreed that districts should not use these indicators to make high-stakes decisions, like whether to fire teachers or add bonuses to paychecks.

Further, it’s questionable how effective it is as a policy to focus simply on individual teacher quality, when poverty has a greater impact on a child’s learning:

The federal Coleman Report issued [in 1966] found that a child’s family economic status was the most telling predictor of school achievement. That stubborn fact remains discomfiting—but undisputed—among education researchers today.

These should all be familiar concerns by now. What this article adds is a much richer picture of the historical and political context for the many players in the debate. I’m deeply disturbed that NYS Supreme Court Judge Cynthia Kern ruled that “there is no requirement that data be reliable for it to be disclosed.” At least Trontz at the NY Times acknowledges the importance of publishing reliable information as opposed to spurious claims, except he seems to overlook all the arguments against the merits of the data:

If we find the data is so completely botched, or riddled with errors that it would be unfair to release it, then we would have to think very long and hard about releasing it.

That’s the whole point: applying value-added modeling to standardized test scores to fire or reward teachers is unreliable to the point of being unfair. Adding noise and confusion to the conversation isn’t “a net positive,” as Arthur Browne from The Daily News seems to believe; it degrades the discussion, at great harm to the individual teachers, their students, the institutions that house them, and the society that purports to sustain them and benefit from them.

Look for the story behind the numbers, not the numbers alone

This time I’ll let the journalists get away with their fondness for reporting the compelling individual story, since the single counterexample is the whole point here.

High-stakes testing was bad enough. But high-stakes evaluating and hiring? This is a great example of the dangers of applying quantitative metrics inappropriately. While value-added modeling may be able to capture properties of the aggregate, it makes occasional errors at the level of the individual. Just one error (whether it’s a factual or exaggerated case, it still illustrates the point) demonstrates the ethical and managerial problems in firing the wrong person based on aggregated data.

Nor do I understand the political eagerness to fire teachers so readily. I’m not convinced that teachers are such an abundant resource that we can afford to burn through them so callously. With teacher shortages in multiple areas and a national teacher attrition rate of 15-20%, we would do better to keep, train, and support the teachers we already have, rather than toss them out and discourage new recruits from joining an increasingly unfriendly profession.

While I agree that it’s important to judge teaching by its merits rather than just the years spent, we need to formulate those measurements carefully. Test scores alone give a misleading illusion of greater precision than they actually have and

Problems with pay-for-performance

If pay-for-performance doesn’t work in medicine, what should our expectations be for its success in education?

“No matter how we looked at the numbers, the evidence was unmistakable; by no measure did pay-for-performance benefit patients with hypertension,” says lead author Brian Serumaga.

Interestingly, hypertension is “a condition where other interventions such as patient education have shown to be very effective.”

According to Anthony Avery… “Doctor performance is based on many factors besides money that were not addressed in this program: patient behavior, continuing MD training, shared responsibility and teamwork with pharmacists, nurses and other health professionals. These are factors that reach far beyond simple monetary incentives.”

It’s not hard to complete the analogy: doctor = teacher; patient = student; MD training = pre-service and in-service professional development; pharmacists, nurses and other health professionals =  lots of other education professionals.

One may question whether the problem is that money is an insufficient motivator, that pay-for-performance amounts to ambiguous global rather than specific local feedback, or that there are too many other factors not well under the doctor’s control to reveal an effect. Still, this does give pause to efforts to incentivize teachers by paying them for their students’ good test scores.

B. Serumaga, D. Ross-Degnan, A. J. Avery, R. A. Elliott, S. R. Majumdar, F. Zhang, S. B. Soumerai. Effect of pay for performance on the management and outcomes of hypertension in the United Kingdom: interrupted time series study. BMJ, 2011; 342 (jan25 3): d108 DOI: 10.1136/bmj.d108

 

Some limitations of value-added modeling

Following this discussion on teacher evaluation led me to a fascinating analysis by Jim Manzi.

We’ve already discussed some concerns with using standardized test scores as the outcome measures in value-added modeling; Manzi points out other problems with the model and the inputs to the model.

  1. Teaching is complex.
  2. It’s difficult to make good predictions about achievement across different domains.
  3. It’s unrealistic to attribute success or failure only to a single teacher.
  4. The effects of teaching extend beyond one school year, and therefore measurements capture influences that go back beyond one year and one teacher.

I’m not particularly fond of the above list—while I agree with all the claims, they’re not explained very clearly and they don’t capture the below key issues, which he discusses in more depth.

  1. Inferences about the aggregate are not inferences about an individual.
  2. More deeply, the model is valid at the aggregate level, “but any one data point cannot be validated.” This is a fundamental problem, true of stereotypes, of generalizations, and of averages. While they may enable you to make broad claims about a population of people, you can’t apply those claims to policies about a particular individual with enough confidence to justify high-stakes outcomes such as firing decisions. As Manzi summarizes it, an evaluation system works to help an organization achieve an outcome, not to be fair to the individuals within that organization.

    This is also related to problems with data mining—by throwing a bunch of data into a model and turning the crank, you can end up with all kinds of difficult-to-interpret correlations which are excellent predictors but which don’t make a whole lot of sense from a theoretical standpoint.

  3. Basing decisions on single instead of multiple measures is flawed.
  4. From a statistical modeling perspective, it’s easier to work with a single precise, quantitative measure than with multiple measures. But this inflates the influence of that one measure, which is often limited in time and scale. Figuring out how to combine multiple measures into a single metric requires subjective judgment (and thus organizational agreement), and, in Manzi’s words, “is very unlikely to work” with value-added modeling. (I do wish he’d expanded on this point further, though.)

  5. All assessments are proxies.
  6. If the proxy is given more value than the underlying phenomenon it’s supposed to measure, this can incentivize “teaching to the test”. With much at stake, some people will try to game the system. This may motivate those who construct and rely on the model to periodically change the metrics, but that introduces more instability in interpreting and calibrating the results across implementations.

In highlighting these weaknesses of value-added modeling, Manzi concludes by arguing that improving teacher evaluation requires a lot more careful interpretation of its results, within the context of better teacher management. I would very much welcome hearing more dialogue about what that management and leadership should look like, instead of so much hype about impressive but complex statistical tools expected to solve the whole problem on their own.

Using student evaluations to measure teaching effectiveness

I came across a fascinating discussion on the use of student evaluations to measure teaching effectiveness upon following this Observational Epidemiology blog post by Mark, a statistical consultant. The original paper by Scott Carrell and James West uses value-added modeling to estimate teachers’ contributions to students’ grades in introductory courses and in subsequent courses, then analyzes the relationship between those contributions and student evaluations. (An ungated version of the paper is also available.) Key conclusions are:

Student evaluations are positively correlated with contemporaneous professor value‐added and negatively correlated with follow‐on student achievement. That is, students appear to reward higher grades in the introductory course but punish professors who increase deep learning (introductory course professor value‐added in follow‐on courses).

We find that less experienced and less qualified professors produce students who perform significantly better in the contemporaneous course being taught, whereas more experienced and highly qualified professors produce students who perform better in the follow‐on related curriculum.

Not having closely followed the research on this, I’ll simply note some key comments from other blogs.

Direct examination:

Several have posted links that suggest an endorsement of this paper’s conclusion, such as George Mason University professor of economics Tyler Cowen, Harvard professor of economics Greg Mankiw, and Northwestern professor of managerial economics Sandeep Baliga. Michael Bishop, a contributor to Permutations (“official blog of the Mathematical Sociology Section of the American Sociological Association“), provides some more detail in his analysis:

In my post on Babcock’s and Marks’ research, I touched on the possible unintended consequences of student evaluations of professors.  This paper gives new reasons for concern (not to mention much additional evidence, e.g. that physical attractiveness strongly boosts student evaluations).

That said, the scary thing is that even with random assignment, rich data, and careful analysis there are multiple, quite different, explanations.

The obvious first possibility is that inexperienced professors, (perhaps under pressure to get good teaching evaluations) focus strictly on teaching students what they need to know for good grades.  More experienced professors teach a broader curriculum, the benefits of which you might take on faith but needn’t because their students do better in the follow-up course!

After citing this alternative explanation from the authors:

Students of low value added professors in the introductory course may increase effort in follow-on courses to help “erase” their lower than expected grade in the introductory course.

Bishop also notes that motivating students to invest more effort in future courses would be a desirable effect of good professors as well. (But how to distinguish between “good” and “bad” methods for producing this motivation isn’t obvious.)

Cross-examination:

Others critique the article and defend the usefulness of student evaluations with observations that provoke further fascinating discussions.

Andrew Gelman, Columbia professor of statistics and political science, expresses skepticism about the claims:

Carrell and West estimate that the effects of instructors on performance in the follow-on class is as large as the effects on the class they’re teaching. This seems hard to believe, and it seems central enough to their story that I don’t know what to think about everything else in the paper.

At Education Sector, Forrest Hinton expresses strong reservations about the conclusions and the methods:

If you’re like me, you are utterly perplexed by a system that would mostly determine the quality of a Calculus I instructor by students’ performance in a Calculus II or aeronautical engineering course taught by a different instructor, while discounting students’ mastery of Calculus I concepts.

The trouble with complex value-added models, like the one used in this report, is that the number of people who have the technical skills necessary to participate in the debate and critique process is very limited—mostly to academics themselves, who have their own special interests.

Jeff Ely, Northwestern professor of economics, objects to the authors’ interpretation of their results:

I don’t see any way the authors have ruled out the following equally plausible explanation for the statistical findings.  First, students are targeting a GPA.  If I am an outstanding teacher and they do unusually well in my class they don’t need to spend as much effort in their next class as those who had lousy teachers, did poorly this time around, and have some catching up to do next time.  Second, students recognize when they are being taught by an outstanding teacher and they give him good evaluations.

In agreement, Ed Dolan, an economist who was also for ten years “a teacher and administrator in a graduate business program that did not have tenure,” comments on Jeff Ely’s blog:

I reject the hypothesis that students give high evaluations to instructors who dumb down their courses, teach to the test, grade high, and joke a lot in class. On the contrary, they resent such teachers because they are not getting their money’s worth. I observed a positive correlation between overall evaluation scores and a key evaluation-form item that indicated that the course required more work than average. Informal conversations with students known to be serious tended to confirm the formal evaluation scores.

Re-direct:

Dean Eckles, PhD candidate at Stanford’s CHIMe lab offers this response to Andrew Gelman’s blog post (linked above):

Students like doing well on tests etc. This happens when the teacher is either easier (either through making evaluations easier or teaching more directly to the test) or more effective.

Conditioning on this outcome, is conditioning on a collider that introduces a negative dependence between teacher quality and other factors affecting student satisfaction (e.g., how easy they are).

From Jeff Ely’s blog, a comment by Brian Moore raises this critical question:

“Second, students recognize when they are being taught by an outstanding teacher and they give him good evaluations.”

Do we know this for sure? Perhaps they know when they have an outstanding teacher, but by definition, those are relatively few.

Closing thoughts:

These discussions raise many key questions, namely:

  • how to measure good teaching;
  • tensions between short-term and long-term assessment and evaluation[1];
  • how well students’ grades measure learning, and how grades impact their perception of learning;
  • the relationship between learning, motivation, and affect (satisfaction);
  • but perhaps most deeply, the question of student metacognition.

The anecdotal comments others have provided about how students respond on evaluations are more fairly couched in the terms “some students.” Given the considerable variability among students, interpreting student evaluations needs to account for those individual differences in teasing out the actual teaching and learning that underlie self-reported perceptions. Buried within those evaluations may be a valuable signal masked by a lot of noise– or more problematically, multiple signals that cancel and drown each other out.

[1] For example, see this review of research demonstrating that training which produces better short-term performance can produce worse long-term learning:
Schmidt, R.A., & Bjork, R.A. (1992). New conceptualizations of practice: Common principles in three paradigms suggest new concepts for training. Psychological Science, 3, 207-217.

Retrieval is only part of the picture

The latest educational research to make the rounds has been reported variously as “Test-Taking Cements Knowledge Better Than Studying,” “Simple Recall Exercises Make Science Learning Easier,” “Practising Retrieval is Best Tool for Learning,” and “Learning Science: Actively Recalling Information from Memory Beats Elaborate Study Methods.” Before anyone gets carried away seeking to apply these findings to practice, let’s correct the headlines and clarify what the researchers actually studied.

First, the “test-taking” vs. “studying” dichotomy presented by the NYT is too broad. The winning condition was “retrieval practice”, described fairly as “actively recalling information from memory” or even “simple recall exercises.” The multiple-choice questions popular on so many standardized tests don’t qualify because they assess recognition of information, not recall. In this study, participants had to report as much information as they could remember from the text, a more generative task than picking the best among the possible answers presented to them.

Nor were the comparison conditions merely “studying.” While the worst-performing conditions asked students to read (and perhaps reread) the text, they were dropped from the second experiment, which contrasted retrieval practice against “elaborative concept-mapping.” Thus, the “elaborate” (better read as “elaborative”) study methods reported in the ScienceDaily headline are overly broad, since concept-mapping is only one of many kinds of elaborative study methods. That the researchers found no benefit for students who had previous concept-mapping experience may simply mean that it requires more than one or two exposures to be useful.

The premise underlying concept-mapping as a learning tool is that re-representing knowledge in another format helps students identify and understand relationships between the concepts. But producing a new representation on paper (or some other external medium) doesn’t require constructing a new internal mental representation. In focusing on producing a concept map, students may simply have copied the information from the text to their diagram without deeply processing what they were writing or drawing. By scoring the concept maps by completeness (number of ideas) rather than quality (appropriateness of node placement and links), this study did not fully safeguard against this.

To a certain extent that may be the exact point the researchers wanted to make: That concept-mapping can be executed in an “active” yet non-generative fashion. Even reviewing a concept map (as the participants were encouraged to do with any remaining time) can be done very superficially, simply checking to make sure that all the information is present, rather than reflecting on the relationships represented—similar to making a “cheat sheet” for a test and trusting that all the formulas and definitions are there, instead of evaluating the conditions and rationale for applying them.

One may construe this as an argument against concept-mapping as a study technique, if it is so difficult to utilize it effectively. But just because a given tool can be used poorly does not mean it should be avoided completely; that could be true of any teaching or learning approach. Nor does this necessarily constitute an argument against other elaborative study methods. Explaining a text or diagram, whether to oneself or to others, is another form of elaboration that has been well documented for its effectiveness in supporting learning[1]. This constitutes an interesting hybrid between elaboration and retrieval, insofar as explanation adds information beyond the source but may also demand partial recall of the contents of the source even when present. If the value of explanation is solely in the retrieval involved, then it should fare worse against pure retrieval and better against pure elaboration.

All of this begs the question, “Better for what?” The tests in this study primarily measured retrieval, with 84% of the points counting the presence of ideas and the rest (from only two questions) assessing inference. Yet even those inference questions depended partially on retrieval, making it ambiguous whether wrong answers reflected a failure to retrieve, comprehend, or apply knowledge. What this study showed most clearly was that retrieval practice is valuable for improving retrieval. Elaboration and other activities may still be valuable for promoting transfer and inference. There could also be a possible interaction whereby elaboration and retrieval mutually enhance each other, since remembering and conducting inferences is easier with robust knowledge structures. The lesson may not be that elaborative activities are a poor use of time, but that they need to incorporate retrieval practice to be most effective.

I don’t at all doubt the validity of the finding, or the importance of retrieval in promoting learning. I share the authors’ frustration with the often-empty trumpeting of “active learning,” which can assume ineffective and meaningless forms [2][3]. I also recognize the value of knowing certain information in order to utilize it efficiently and flexibly. My concerns are in interpreting and applying this finding sensibly to real-life teaching and learning.

  • Retrieval is only part of the picture. Educators need to assess and support multiple skills, including and beyond retrieval. There’s a great danger of forgetting other learning goals (such as understanding, applying, creating, evaluating, etc.) when pressured to document success in retrieval.
  • Is it retrieving knowledge or generating knowledge? I also wonder whether “retrieval” may be too narrow a label for the broader phenomenon of generating knowledge. This may be a specific instance of the well-documented generation effect [4], and it may not always be most beneficial to focus only on retrieving the particular facts. There could be a similar advantage to other generative tasks, such as inventing a new application of a given phenomenon, writing a story incorporating new vocabulary words, or creating a problem that could almost be solved by a particular strategy. None of these require retrieving the phenomenon, the definitions, or the solution method to be learned, but they all require elaborating upon the knowledge-to-be-learned by generating new information and deeper understanding of it. Knowledge is more than a list of disconnected facts [5]; it needs a structure to be meaningful [6]. Focusing too heavily on retrieving the list downplays the importance of developing the supporting structure.
  • Retrieval isn’t recognition, and not all retrieval is worthwhile. Most important, I’m especially concerned that the mainstream media’s reporting of this finding may make it too easily misinterpreted. It would be a shame if this were used to justify more multiple-choice testing, or if a well-meaning student thought that accurately reproducing a graph from a textbook by memory constituted better studying than explaining the relationships embedded within that graph.

For the sake of a healthy relationship between research and practice, I hope the general public and policymakers will take this finding in context and not champion it into the latest silver bullet that will save education. Careless conversion of research into practice undermines the scientific process, effective policymaking, and teachers’ professional judgment, all of which need to collaborate instead of collide.

J. D. Karpicke, J. R. Blunt. Retrieval Practice Produces More Learning than Elaborative Studying with Concept Mapping. Science, 2011; DOI: 10.1126/science.1199327


[1] Chi, M.T.H., de Leeuw, N., Chiu, M.H., & LaVancher, C. (1994). Eliciting self-explanations improves understanding. Cognitive Science, 18, 439-477.
[2] For example, see the “Teacher A” model described in:
Scardamalia, M., & Bereiter, C. (1991). Higher levels of agency for children in knowledge building: A challenge for the design of new knowledge media. Journal of the Learning Sciences, 1, 37-68.
(There’s also a “Johnny Appleseed” project description I once read that’s a bit of a caricature of poorly-designed project-based learning, but I can’t seem to find it now. If anyone knows of this example, please share it with me!)
[3] This is one reason why some educators now advocate “minds-on” rather than simply “hands-on” learning. Of course, what those minds are focused on still deserves better clarification.
[4] e.g., Slamecka, N.J., & Graf, P. (1978). The generation effect: Delineation of a phenomenon. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Human Learning and Memory, 4, 592-604.
[5] In the following study, some gifted students outscored historians in their fact recall, but could not evaluate and interpret claims as effectively:
Wineburg, S.S. (1991). Historical problem solving: A study of the cognitive processes used in the evaluation of documentary and pictorial evidence. Journal of Educational Psychology, 83, 73-87.
[6] For a fuller description of the importance of structured knowledge representations, see:
Bransford, J.D., Brown, A.L., & Cocking, R.R. (2000). How people learn: Brain, mind, experience, and school (Expanded edition). Washington DC: National Academy Press, pp. 31-50 (Ch. 2: How Experts Differ from Novices). 

Judging books by their covers

On “Corruption in textbook-adoption proceedings: ‘Judging Books by Their Covers‘”:

In 1964 the eminent physicist Richard Feynman served on the State of California’s Curriculum Commission and saw how the Commission chose math textbooks for use in California’s public schools. In his acerbic memoir of that experience, titled “Judging Books by Their Covers,” Feynman analyzed the Commission’s idiotic method of evaluating books, and he described some of the tactics employed by schoolbook salesmen who wanted the Commission to adopt their shoddy products. “Judging Books by Their Covers” appeared as a chapter in “Surely You’re Joking, Mr. Feynman!” — Feynman’s autobiographical book that was published in 1985 by W.W. Norton & Company.

The perils of averaging (or poorly selected crowd-sourcing), biased presentations, and careless writing and reviewing.

%d bloggers like this: